Game theory

Bertrand paradox (economics)

In economics and commerce, the Bertrand paradox — named after its creator, Joseph Bertrand — describes a situation in which two players (firms) reach a state of Nash equilibrium where both firms charge a price equal to marginal cost ("MC"). The paradox is that in models such as Cournot competition, an increase in the number of firms is associated with a convergence of prices to marginal costs. In these alternative models of oligopoly, a small number of firms earn positive profits by charging prices above cost.Suppose two firms, A and B, sell a homogeneous commodity, each with the same cost of production and distribution, so that customers choose the product solely on the basis of price. It follows that demand is infinitely price-elastic. Neither A nor B will set a higher price than the other because doing so would yield the entire market to their rival. If they set the same price, the companies will share both the market and profits. On the other hand, if either firm were to lower its price, even a little, it would gain the whole market and substantially larger profits. Since both A and B know this, they will each try to undercut their competitor until the product is selling at zero economic profit. This is the pure-strategy Nash equilibrium. Recent work has shown that there may be an additional mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium with positive economic profits under the assumption that monopoly profits are infinite. For the case of finite monopoly profits, it has been shown that positive profits under price competition are impossible in mixed equilibria and even in the more general case of correlated equilibria. The Bertrand paradox rarely appears in practice because real products are almost always differentiated in some way other than price (brand name, if nothing else); firms have limitations on their capacity to manufacture and distribute, and two firms rarely have identical costs. Bertrand's result is paradoxical because if the number of firms goes from one to two, the price decreases from the monopoly price to the competitive price and stays at the same level as the number of firms increases further. This is not very realistic, as in reality, markets featuring a small number of firms with market power typically charge a price in excess of marginal cost. The empirical analysis shows that in most industries with two competitors, positive profits are made. Solutions to the Paradox attempt to derive solutions that are more in line with solutions from the Cournot model of competition, where two firms in a market earn positive profits that lie somewhere between the perfectly competitive and monopoly levels. Some reasons the Bertrand paradox do not strictly apply: * Capacity constraints. Sometimes firms do not have enough capacity to satisfy all demand. This was a point first raised by Francis Edgeworth and gave rise to the Bertrand–Edgeworth model. * Integer pricing. Prices higher than MC are ruled out because one firm can undercut another by an arbitrarily small amount. If prices are discrete (for example have to take integer values) then one firm has to undercut the other by at least one cent. This implies that the price one cent above MC is now an equilibrium: if the other firm sets the price one cent above MC, the other firm can undercut it and capture the whole market, but this will earn it no profit. It will prefer to share the market 50/50 with the other firm and earn strictly positive profits. * Product differentiation. If products of different firms are differentiated, then consumers may not switch completely to the product with lower price. * Dynamic competition. Repeated interaction or repeated price competition can lead to the price above MC in equilibrium. * More money for higher price. It follows from repeated interaction: If one company sets their price slightly higher, then they will still get about the same amount of buys but more profit for each buy, so the other company will raise their price, and so on (only in repeated games, otherwise the price dynamics are in the other direction). * Oligopoly. If the two companies can agree on a price, it is in their long-term interest to keep the agreement: the revenue from cutting prices is less than twice the revenue from keeping the agreement and lasts only until the other firm cuts its own prices. * Effort to Purchase. If there is a difference in the effort it takes for a consumer to purchase one over the other based on the consumer's circumstances (such as a difference in travel time to stores that stock the products), this can cause consumers to prefer one product over the other even if the product itself is exactly the same. * Social Interdependence. If indifferent consumers are treated as having a strategic choice between products based on loyalty and the choices of others the firms can achieve a price equilibrium with positive profits without directly violating Bertrand's assumptions. * Goodwill. Even when confronted with otherwise identical products in a market of price competition the two companies are themselves inherently different entities which may influence a consumer's choice of product via brand goodwill. * Status Quo. Consumers have an observed bias for retaining status quo so even when a new firm with identical product enters a market, consumers are biased to continue to purchase from the original firm. * Customer Heterogeneity. While products may be homogenous, heterogenous consumers can still create a market in which two price competing firms achieve price equilibrium with positive profits. (Wikipedia).

Video thumbnail

Mod-03 Lec-17 Different Aspects of Bertrand Model

Game Theory and Economics by Dr. Debarshi Das, Department of Humanities and Social Sciences, IIT Guwahati. For more details on NPTEL visit http://nptel.iitm.ac.in

From playlist IIT Guwahati: Game Theory and Economics | CosmoLearning.org Economics

Video thumbnail

2. Utilities, Endowments, and Equilibrium

Financial Theory (ECON 251) This lecture explains what an economic model is, and why it allows for counterfactual reasoning and often yields paradoxical conclusions. Typically, equilibrium is defined as the solution to a system of simultaneous equations. The most important economic mode

From playlist Financial Theory with John Geanakoplos

Video thumbnail

Episode 4: Micro vs Macro

What's the difference between Microeconomics and Macroeconomics? "Episode 4: Micro vs Macro" by Dr. Mary J. McGlasson is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs 3.0 Unported License.

From playlist Microeconomics modules

Video thumbnail

Meaning of Lagrange multiplier

In the previous videos on Lagrange multipliers, the Lagrange multiplier itself has just been some proportionality constant that we didn't care about. Here, you can see what its real meaning is.

From playlist Multivariable calculus

Video thumbnail

The Easiest Problem Everyone Gets Wrong

We know how difficult the Monty Hall Problem is for so many people even after they’re shown all the math behind the best possible strategy. It’s basic probability, but it’s deceptive -- and it all started with the Bertrand’s Box Paradox. In this video, I go back to the origins of a probab

From playlist Prob and Stats

Video thumbnail

Lagrange multipliers: 2 constraints

Free ebook http://tinyurl.com/EngMathYT A lecture showing how to apply the method of Lagrange multipliers where two contraints are involved.

From playlist Lagrange multipliers

Video thumbnail

Bertrand Russell's Barber Paradox

SUPPORT CR on PATREON: http://bit.ly/2qBHcvf ADDITIONAL ASSUMPTIONS: 1. Everyone is male. 2. The townspeople can only shave themselves or be shaved by the barber, they cannot shave anyone else. 3. The barber must be shaved. Logical paradoxes are some of the most infuriating and frustr

From playlist Concerning Everything

Video thumbnail

What is Bertrand Russels Barber Paradox?

Logical paradoxes are some of the most infuriating and frustrating problems that we can try to solve. As humans, we always want to find an answer and we naturally assume that an answer must exist. In the case of Bertrand Russell's Barber Paradox, a solution does exist, but it becomes even

From playlist Concerning Questions

Video thumbnail

Fill In The Blank (Dynamics/Friction)

#Physics #Dynamics #Engineering #TikTok #NicholasGKK #shorts

From playlist Mechanical Engineering

Video thumbnail

Bertrand's Paradox (with 3blue1brown) - Numberphile

Featuring Grant Sanderson, creator of 3blue1brown. Extra footage from this interview: https://youtu.be/pJyKM-7IgAU 3blue1brown video on the shadow a cube: https://youtu.be/ltLUadnCyi0 More links & stuff in full description below ↓↓↓ 3blue1brown: https://www.youtube.com/channel/UCYO_jab_e

From playlist Guest appearances on other channels

Video thumbnail

Russell's Paradox - A Ripple in the Foundations of Mathematics

Bertrand Russell's set theory paradox on the foundations of mathematics, axiomatic set theory and the laws of logic. A celebration of Gottlob Frege. Thank you to Professor Joel David Hamkins for your help with this video. Hi! I'm Jade. Subscribe to Up and Atom for physics, math and com

From playlist Math

Video thumbnail

Pricing Options using Black Scholes Merton

These classes are all based on the book Trading and Pricing Financial Derivatives, available on Amazon at this link. https://amzn.to/2WIoAL0 Check out our website http://www.onfinance.org/ Follow Patrick on twitter here: https://twitter.com/PatrickEBoyle The Black–Scholes or Black–Scho

From playlist Class 3: Pricing Financial Options

Video thumbnail

Barber & Russell Paradoxes (History of Undecidability Part 2) - Computerphile

$20 off your 1st purchase at www.LittleBits.com use the code “COMPUTERPHILE” The Barber Paradox: Professor Brailsford continues the history of undecidability. History of Undecidability Part1: http://youtu.be/nsZsd5qtbo4 Turing & The Halting Problem: http://youtu.be/macM_MtS_w4 http://

From playlist The History of Undecidability

Video thumbnail

Turing Meets Paradoxes (History of Undecidability Part 3) - Computerphile

Taking a solemn oath to promise never to write a program that analyses other programs? - That's how Professor Brailsford felt when he first understood undecidability. Latest in our series on the History of Undecidability Undecidability Tangent (History of Undecidability Part 1): http://y

From playlist The History of Undecidability

Video thumbnail

Logic: The Structure of Reason

As a tool for characterizing rational thought, logic cuts across many philosophical disciplines and lies at the core of mathematics and computer science. Drawing on Aristotle’s Organon, Russell’s Principia Mathematica, and other central works, this program tracks the evolution of logic, be

From playlist Logic & Philosophy of Mathematics

Video thumbnail

Lagrange multiplier example: Minimizing a function subject to a constraint

Free ebook http://tinyurl.com/EngMathYT I discuss and solve a simple problem through the method of Lagrange multipliers. A function is required to be minimized subject to a constraint equation. Such an example is seen in 2nd-year university mathematics.

From playlist Lagrange multipliers

Video thumbnail

Multivariable Calculus | Differentiability

We give the definition of differentiability for a multivariable function and provide a few examples. http://www.michael-penn.net https://www.researchgate.net/profile/Michael_Penn5 http://www.randolphcollege.edu/mathematics/

From playlist Multivariable Calculus

Video thumbnail

1.11.9 Russell's Paradox: Video

MIT 6.042J Mathematics for Computer Science, Spring 2015 View the complete course: http://ocw.mit.edu/6-042JS15 Instructor: Albert R. Meyer License: Creative Commons BY-NC-SA More information at http://ocw.mit.edu/terms More courses at http://ocw.mit.edu

From playlist MIT 6.042J Mathematics for Computer Science, Spring 2015

Video thumbnail

Why bias an average? // An intro to DLS and particle size measurement

An introduction to Dynamic Light Scattering (DLS), micro/nano-particle size measurement, and the application of weighted averages. Submitted to #SoME2 https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=hZuYICAEN9Y The original Numberphile and 3Blue1Brown videos on Bertrand's Paradox: https://www.youtube.c

From playlist Summer of Math Exposition 2 videos

Video thumbnail

Convexity and The Principle of Duality

A gentle and visual introduction to the topic of Convex Optimization (part 2/3). In this video, we give the definition of convex sets, convex functions, and convex optimization problems. We also present a beautiful and extremely useful notion in convexity optimization, which is the princ

From playlist Convex Optimization

Related pages

Cournot competition | Nash equilibrium | Prisoner's dilemma | Edgeworth paradox | Status quo bias | Joseph Bertrand | Correlated equilibrium | Bertrand–Edgeworth model | Marginal cost